The US has run a assive trade deficit for over 30 years. In recent times, there has been a growing chorus of commentators who seek to place the blame on our trading partners, most notably China, just as in an earlier time others had targeted Japan and Germany. It is said that the problem stems not from our reduced international competitiveness, but rather from the manipulation of exchange rates by our more successful trading partners.
This claim is not based on any direct evidence, but rather on an inference derived from standard international trade theory, which predicts that free trade will automatically lead to balanced trade. From this particular theoretical perspective, our large and persistent large trade deficit must be rooted in some obstacles to free trade. The large surpluses of our trading partners such as China then make them natural candidates for our opprobrium. Of course, if the standard theory is incorrect, this line of inference collapses. I wish to argue that the standard theory is wrong, on both theoretical and empirical grounds, and that free trade does not automatically eliminate trade imbalances. On the contrary, free trade reflects international competitiveness, and persistent trade deficits are symptoms of persistent competitive weakness.
The theory of international trade is actually a subset of the general theory of competition. In a business driven world, international trade is largely conducted by businesses. Domestic exporters sell to foreign importers who in turn sell to their residents, while domestic importers buy from foreign exporters and sell to us. At each step in the chain, it is profit that motivates the business decision. Standard (comparative cost) theory rests on the proposition that a trade deficit in a country will drive down the real price of its currency, which in turn will reduce the deficit, until at some point both the balance of trade and the balance of payments are automatically reduced to zero. A trade surplus would have the opposite initial effect, bringing once again back this double balance. When the nominal exchange rate was fixed, as it was during the Bretton Woods era, a trade deficit generates a money outflow, and this is assumed to lower the national price level, thereby making the country’s goods more competitive on a world scale. When the exchange rate is flexible, as it has been since the collapse of the Bretton Woods agreement in the early 1970s, a trade deficit is assumed to depreciate the currency, once again making the country more competitive on the world market. In either case, the process is supposed to operate until the trade deficit has been eliminated.
In his book International Economics (1957), the eminent Oxford economist Roy Harrod came to a rather different conclusion: in the trade deficit country, the resulting money outflows decrease liquidity and increase interest rates, all through the natural reactions of financial markets; in the trade surplus country, the opposite effect obtains, and interest rates fall. Neither of these substantially alters the trade balance. Instead, they induce short term capital flows into the high interest rate (trade deficit) country from the low interest (trade surplus) country, until the overall balance of payments in each is in equilibrium. In other words, free markets automatically cover trade deficits with international debt, and offset trade surpluses through international lending. As long as neither side does anything to intervene, the differences in international competitiveness, which induced the trade imbalances are maintained, not eliminated. This is why successful countries have always known that one must first build up a country’s competitiveness. In earlier times this was the policy of the UK, Germany, France and the US. In more recent times, it has been that of Japan, South Korea, and China.
In a recent article on China, David Leonhardt says that “there is … no question that China’s currency remains undervalued” because “the huge demand for Chinese goods should be driving up the price of its currency.” Since China’s large trade surplus has not driven up its exchange rate, he concludes that “Beijing has been intervening to prevent that.” Note that this explicitly relies on the standard theory. Leonhardt also cites estimates of the extent to which China’s exchange rate is supposedly undervalued. Yet, all such estimates are also derived from models that assume that balanced trade is the normal outcome of free trade.
Paul Krugman takes the same stance, accusing China of obstructing the “automatic mechanisms” of international trade that would otherwise bring about automatic balance (see here, here, here and here). As a renowned trade theorist in his own right, Krugman explicitly links his inference to the underlying expectation that free trade will automatically lead to balanced trade – a proposition which he has elsewhere called a “sacred tenet” of standard theory.
It is precisely this sacred tenet that I dispute. Trade imbalances are perfectly normal, at both theoretical and empirical levels. This does not exclude the possibility that China intervenes to lower its exchange rate below the free market level. What it tells us is that we cannot simply infer this from the existence of their trade surplus and our trade deficit.
Having consulted different stars, might we not find that at least some part of the fault lies in ourselves?
Free Trade
And The Euro Crisis For Non Economists
http://www.scribd.com/doc/201196367/Free-Trade-And-The-Euro-Crisis-The-Case-of-Greece
I think the problem with argument is the statement that trade deficits decrease liquidity. In a country that has its own currency, liquidity is determined by the central bank.